Skip to main content
About HEC About HEC
Summer School Summer School
Faculty & Research Faculty & Research
Master’s programs Master’s programs
Bachelor Programs Bachelor Programs
MBA Programs MBA Programs
PhD Program PhD Program
Executive Education Executive Education
HEC Online HEC Online
About HEC
Overview Overview
Who
We Are
Who
We Are
Egalité des chances Egalité des chances
HEC Talents HEC Talents
International International
Campus
Life
Campus
Life
Sustainability Sustainability
Diversity
& Inclusion
Diversity
& Inclusion
Stories Stories
The HEC
Foundation
The HEC
Foundation
Summer School
Youth Programs Youth Programs
Summer programs Summer programs
Online Programs Online Programs
Faculty & Research
Overview Overview
Faculty Directory Faculty Directory
Departments Departments
Centers Centers
Chairs Chairs
Grants Grants
Knowledge@HEC Knowledge@HEC
Master’s programs
Master in
Management
Master in
Management
Master's
Programs
Master's
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Summer
Programs
Summer
Programs
Exchange
students
Exchange
students
Student
Life
Student
Life
Our
Difference
Our
Difference
Bachelor Programs
Overview Overview
Course content Course content
Admissions Admissions
Fees and Financing Fees and Financing
MBA Programs
MBA MBA
Executive MBA Executive MBA
TRIUM EMBA TRIUM EMBA
PhD Program
Overview Overview
HEC Difference HEC Difference
Program details Program details
Research areas Research areas
HEC Community HEC Community
Placement Placement
Job Market Job Market
Admissions Admissions
Financing Financing
Executive Education
Home Home
About us About us
Management topics Management topics
Open Programs Open Programs
Custom Programs Custom Programs
Events/News Events/News
Contacts Contacts
HEC Online
Overview Overview
Degree Program Degree Program
Executive certificates Executive certificates
MOOCs MOOCs
Summer Programs Summer Programs
Youth programs Youth programs
Article

Is It Rational to Stockpile in Times of Crisis?

Decision Sciences
Published on:
8 minutes

The health crisis caused by COVID-19 has triggered an economic one. We observe a significant portion of the population fearing shortage of primary consumption goods and marked stockpiling behavior. Because such behavior increases the risk of shortage, several stores have decided to ration some goods, and governments have had to make public announcements to reassure consumers that there would be no shortage. Avoiding consumer stockpiling is hence one of the key aspects of the management of this crisis. But is it rational to stockpile in times of crisis? We review and discuss the rational and irrational aspects of such behavior.

someone cares a big pile of cardboard stacks

©BillionPhotos.com / Adobe Stock

Listen to the podcast in French:

 

Although over-purchasing in times of crisis might be considered as irrational, scholars in economics, operations research and marketing have proposed theoretical models explaining when and how individuals rationally decide to stockpile. Besides rational motives, many behavioral aspects can also motivate over-purchase decisions. 

Stockpiling as a rational decision involving risk and time

Decisions to purchase and store quantities in prevision of future hazards are not infrequent, and may concern not only individuals, but also states and companies. At the State level, decisions to stockpile goods such as oil, weapons, medical masks and drugs are highly strategic. It can also be in the interest of the companies and consumers to stockpile primary or consumption goods, as an insurance against variations of future prices (as in the case of shortage risks).

 

It can be in the interest of the companies and consumers to stockpile primary or consumption goods, as an insurance against variations of future prices.

 

In all these contexts, the decision can be analyzed using the same framework. Stockpiling is a safe but costly option: the costs relate to purchasing additional quantity at the present time rather than smoothing the expense across time, as well as to storage costs (e.g. warehouse space and guarding). Not stockpiling is a risky option that exposes the decision maker to future price variations. 

The best option, or optimal amount of stockpiling is therefore a decision involving risk and time and as such involves many factors: the perceived risk of price variations, the attitude towards time (how the decision maker values future consequences) and the risk attitudes (how the decision maker values risky consequences). In rational decision making these factors are combined using a model called “discounted expected utility”. For example, under this model, a consequence received at a future time period t with a perceived probability p is valued p exp(-rt)u(x), where r is the discount rate that captures attitudes towards the future, and u is a utility function that characterizes risk attitudes. Assuming that the decision maker has well-defined risk perception, discount rate and risk attitudes, the model makes recommendations about how much to stock pile.

 

Decision to stockpile depends on the perceived probability of shortage, risk aversion, discount rate and storage costs.

 

As one could expect, recommended stockpiling will increase with the perceived probability of shortage and risk aversion; it will decrease with the discount rate and storage costs. 

The discounted expected utility model can be used to study many other decisions involving risk and time in various domains such as strategy, finance, marketing and industrial organization.

Deviations from the rational decision-making model

Beyond its normative appeal, the model underlying such recommendations cannot satisfactorily describe observed behavior. See Machina (1987) for violations of this model in the context of risk, and Loewenstein and Prelec (1992) for the context of time. We have investigated several of these anomalies in a recent laboratory experiment where subjects had to make decisions involving both risk and time with real possible gains. We observed systemic deviations from the predictions of the rational model. As previously observed, subjects did not exhibit stable risk attitudes. They took more risks in decisions involving small probabilities than in decisions involving medium or large probabilities. Another result regards the impact of time. Here again, time preferences were not constant.

 

empty shelf in a supermarket
"Observing that other people stockpile creates a social pressure" (©zephy p on AdobeStock)

 

More impatience was observed towards the near future than concerning periods further away in time. This pattern is responsible for several anomalies in decisions involving time, such as reversal of preferences over time or procrastination. Though well documented in the literature, several scholars have hypothesized that this pattern would disappear in decisions involving both risk and time. Our results, recently published in Games and Economic Behavior(1), show that this pattern holds even in these more general contexts. 

Another source of irrational decisions regards the way people perceive risks when probabilities are not available (e.g. Tversky and Kahneman 1974). For example, in their evaluation of the likelihoods of uncertain future events, people generally tend to overestimate rare events and underestimate frequent ones. In another recently published paper, we propose a method for measuring people's beliefs about uncertain events(2) from simple choices. The method allows to put beliefs into numbers and to test if peoples’ perception is accurate.

Another important research question in the decision sciences relates to how people formulate and update their beliefs in the light of available evidence. In the context of stockpiling, decision makers can also be influenced by the behavior of their peers. 

The social dimension of stockpiling: an analogy with bank runs

Stockpiling is an individual decision that can have dire social consequences. Indeed, in the context of shortage risk, individuals deciding to overpurchase effectively contribute to the risk. This kind of situation is called “self-fulfilling prophecy”.

 

Like bank runs, stockpiling decisions show two equilibria: one where decision makers stay calm, one where they panic, leading to a catastrophic situation.

 

When considered as a game involving many players, the decision to stockpile can be studied in game theory and is analogous to bank run games. These games have two equilibria: one where decision makers stay calm and do not overpurchase; another where decision makers panic and decide to overpurchase, leading to a catastrophic situation of real shortage. The first equilibrium is obviously better than the second one. Nevertheless, regarding individual rationality, both are “Nash equilibria”, meaning that when one sees that other people start to stockpile, individual rationality recommends you to stockpile too! In a social context, stockpiling can therefore be considered as a rational but selfish decision. 

The role of herding behavior

Considering stockpiling as a social game introduces the fact that the beliefs and actions of each decision maker can be influenced by the actions of the other decision makers. Updating beliefs after observing the behavior of the others can be rational. Such situations are called information cascades. But behavioral studies reveal that people are sensitive to the behavior of others, even when it is uninformative or even misleading! In particular, people tend to conform to the dominant behavior, even in the absence of rational reasons to do so. In the present case of COVID 19, we can speculate that the sudden but notable stockpiling of toilet paper was due to herding. 

People can probably easily convince themselves that, even if there were a major economic collapse, toilet paper is not the good that need be given the highest priority. However, observing that other people stockpile creates a social pressure: “it is not possible that so many people behave so irrationally: there must be a good reason for them to do so”.

 

Decision science suggests that stockpiling can be rational from an individual perspective. But in practice, people do not stockpile optimally because of individual irrationality and group pressure.

 

Overall, decision science focusing on both individual decision making and game theory suggests that stockpiling can be rational from an individual perspective. However, in practice, there are many reasons to think that people do not stockpile optimally because they violate the rules of individual decision rationality or are irrationally influenced by the behavior of others. 

 

References 

(1)Abdellaoui, M., Kemel, E., Panin, A., & Vieider, F. M. (2019). Measuring time and risk preferences in an integrated framework. Games and Economic Behavior, 115, 459-469.
(2)Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., Kemel, E., & L’Haridon, O. (2017). Measuring beliefs under ambiguity. Operations Research, in press.
Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573-597.
Machina, M. J. (1987). Decision-making in the presence of risk. Science, 236(4801), 537-543.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. science, 185(4157), 1124-1131.

 

Related content on Decision Sciences

Decision Sciences

Risking the future? How Delayed Consequences Can Bias the Perception of Risk

By Emmanuel Kemel

Brian Hill GREGHEC
Brian Hill
CNRS Research Professor
Emmanuel Kemel HEC professor
Emmanuel Kemel
CNRS Research Professor
Economics

How Much to Reveal to Persuade a Decision Maker?

By Tristan Tomala, Marie Laclau, Frédéric Koessler

Photo Credits: Fergregory / Adobe Stock

Decision Sciences

Black Swans and Other Challenges to Rational Decision Making

By Stefania Minardi, Itzhak Gilboa